How will increasing numbers of old geezers affect intellectual property?

Ageing is ever a work-in-progress—just ask this hoary Kat. Beyond individual aches and pains, the subject of ageing and the resulting demographics have increasingly occupied social scientists and policy-makers across various fields. In brief, the argument runs as follows: at the back end, people are living longer, to some extent working longer (either by necessity or choice), on the one hand, but fewer and fewer children are born, at the front end. The result is that fewer and fewer working age people are being called upon to support an increasing number of senior citizens, putting national budgets at risk and threatening social cohesion. Absent from these discussions, however, as best as this Kat can determine, is attention to the question of whether the changing age make-up of populations might have any effect on intellectual property and, in particular, inventive activity.

The data seem to speak for themselves regarding ageing. To ensure population stability (immigration is a separate and often contentious matter), the so-called fertility (or replacement) rate, being the number of children a woman is likely to have during her child-bearing years, has famously been marked as 2.1, whereby two workers will replace their parents as they drop out of the labour force. A fertility rate of above 2.1 (but not too much above) will add additional young workers to support their retired parents and grandparents, while a fertility rate below that number will put increasing pressure on national economies seeking to support their senior citizens. As has been well publicized, many countries especially in Europe and Asia are well below the replacement rate. Thus, for Europe taken as a whole, the replacement rate is 1.6 (being significantly below that in certain Mediterranean and East European countries as well as dropping in Germany); it is around 1.6 in China (largely the result of the one-child policy); it is 1.4 in Japan and 1.3 in South Korea. To the contrary, the numbers in France, Nordic countries and the United States show a replacement rate around 2.1, while Israel, almost alone in the Western world, is at 2.9. Taken as a whole, nearly half of the world’s population may soon not be replacing itself.

All of this is well and good, but what about IP? Let’s start with the basic question: how, if at all, does age affect inventive activity? It seems to this Kat that one proxy for gauging this metric is the distribution of inventors by age. Using five to ten-year age cohorts, is inventive activity, as measured by the number of patents, independent of the age of the inventor, or is there a greater likelihood that a certain age cohort(s) will be engaged in inventions? This Kat is not aware of any of empirical studies on this point (but he would be delighted if any Kat readers could direct him to such research). Indeed, this Kat wonders whether, even in this age of big data in the service of IP (see for example the piece by Kat riend Nigel Swycher in the latest issue of IAM magazine, “Big data solutions to determining IP risk and value”), it is even possible to extract such information.

Let’s assume that such data, at least in some form, can be assembled. What they might be their implications? An insight to this question was suggested in a contrarian piece that appeared on May 31st in The Economist, here. Entitled “Quality time”, with the byline (“Why shrinking populations may no bad thing”), the article (from which some of the data mentioned above was extracted) argued that when education of senior citizens is taken account, the fertility rates need only be between 1.5-1.8 to achieve stability. This is because, as the piece went to conclude:
Better-educated people are more productive and healthier, retire later and live longer. Education levels in most places have been rising and are likely to continue to do so…..Educating more people to a high level will be expensive, both because of the direct costs and because the better-educated start work later. But they will contribute more to the economy throughout their working lives and retire later, so the investment will pay off.
Let’s assume for purposes of argument that there is merit to this conclusion. If so, the ”contribution” to the economy in the form of putting downward pressure on the younger generations of workers to support senior citizens is understandable. But does this “contribution” also mean increased inventive activity? Perhaps extending the working careers of the well-educated will increase the number (and even the so-called “quality”) of patents. If that is a likely outcome, then the observation made in the article should be brought to bear on the analysis of the effects of ageing on inventive activity. But assume, to the contrary, that inventive activity is skewed to young age cohorts. In that case, the presumed benefits from increasing education on altering the dependency ratio between the young and the elderly might actually be offset to some extent by the extended presence of less inventive senior citizens in the productive workplace (who might even block the market entry of potentially inventive younger employees). Given the potential import of which outcome is more likely, obtaining good data to reach informed decisions seems to this Kat to be a matter of particular importance.